Land Revenue Policy of British in India

  • Land revenue was one of the major sources of income for Britishers in India. There were broadly three types of land revenue policies in existence during the British rule in India.
  • Before independence, there were three major types of land tenure systems prevailing in the country:
    • The Zamindari System
    • The Mahalwari System
    • The Ryotwari System
  • The basic difference in these systems was regarding the mode of payment of land revenue.

The Zamindari System

  • The zamindari system was introduced by Lord Cornwallis in 1793 through Permanent Settlement that fixed the land rights of the members in perpetuity without any provision for fixed rent or occupancy right for actual cultivators.
  • Under the Zamindari system, the land revenue was collected from the farmers by the intermediaries known as Zamindars.
  • The share of the government in the total land revenue collected by the zamindars was kept at 10/11th, and the remainder going to zamindars.
  • The system was most prevalent in West Bengal, Bihar, Odisha, UP, Andhra Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh.

The Permanent Settlement Agreement

  • According to the Permanent Land revenue settlement the Zamindars were recognised as the permanent owners of the land.
  • They were given instruction to pay 89% of the annual revenue to the state and were permitted to enjoy 11% of the revenue as their share.
  • The Zamindars were left independent in the internal affairs of their respective districts.

Issues with the Zamindari System

  • For the Cultivators: In villages, the cultivators found the system oppressive and exploitative as the rent they paid to the zamindar was very high while his right on the land was quite insecure.
    • The cultivators often had to take loan to pay the rents, on failing to pay the rent, they were evicted from the land.
  • For the Zamindars: The revenue had been fixed so high that the zamindars found it difficult to pay, and those who failed to pay the revenue lost their zamindari.
    • The zamindars were not so keen about improving the land. As long as they could give out the land and get rent, they preferred it.
  • For the Company: By the first decade of the 19th century, the cultivation slowly expanded and prices rose in the market.
    • Although this meant an increase in the income of Zamindars, it was no gain for the company since it could not increase a revenue demand that had been settled permanently.

The Ryotwari System

  • In the British territories in southern India, there was a move away from the idea of Permanent Settlement.
  • A system that came to be known as the Ryotwari System, was devised by Captain Alexander Read and Sir Thomas Munro at the end of the 18th century and introduced by the latter when he was governor of Madras Presidency (1819–26).
  • Under the Ryotwari system, the land revenue was paid by the farmers directly to the state.
  • In this system, the Individual cultivator called Ryot had full rights regarding sale, transfer, and leasing of the land.
    • The ryots could not be evicted from their land as long as they paid the rent.
  • It was prevalent in most of southern India, first introduced in Tamil Nadu. It was later extended to Maharashtra, Berar, East Punjab, Coorg and Assam.
  • The advantages of this system were the elimination of middlemen, who often oppressed villagers.

Issues with the Ryotwari System

  • This system gave much power to subordinate revenue officials, whose activities were inadequately supervised.
  • The system was dominated by the mahajans and moneylenders who granted loans to cultivators by mortgaging their land.
  • The moneylenders exploited the cultivators and evicted them from their land in case of loan default.

The Mahalwari System

  • By the early 19th century, the Company officials were convinced that the system of revenue had to be changed again.
    • The revenues cannot be fixed permanently at such a time when the Company needed more money to meet its expenses of administration and trade.
  • In 1822, Englishman Holt Mackenzie devised a new system known as the Mahalwari System in the North Western Provinces of the Bengal Presidency (most of this area is now in Uttar Pradesh).
  • Under the Mahalwari system, the land revenue was collected from the farmers by the village headmen on behalf of the whole village (and not the zamindar).
  • The entire village was converted into one bigger unit called ‘Mahal’ and was treated as one unit for the payment of land revenue.
    • The revenue under the Mahalwari system was to be revised periodically and not fixed permanently.
  • The system was popularised by Lord William Bentick in Agra and Awadh and was later extended to Madhya Pradesh and Punjab.

Issue with the Mahalwari System

  • A major drawback of the system was that the survey was practically based on faulty assumptions which left a space for manipulations and corruption.
  • At times, it made the Company spend more for the collection than the revenue collected. Consequently, the system was regarded as a failure.

Implications of Land Revenue Policy of British

With such hefty taxes levied under the three land revenue policies, there were certain implications, such as:

  • Absentee landlordism: The Company's land revenue systems were exploitative in nature. It created landlordism in some parts and peasant proprietorship in some other regions.
    • In Bengal, it led to the emergence of absentee landlordism.
  • Commercialisation of agriculture: Since the rate of revenue under the Company's land revenue system was excessive, the peasants started producing all those crops with high market value. It is known as the commercialisation of agriculture.
  • It led to the change from home consumption to market consumption.
  • Therefore, cash crops like cotton, sugarcane, jute, etc. began to be cultivated.
  • Social impact: Land revenue policies had progressive significance over a period of time. It led to the disappearance of old rigidities like caste in village life and led to the emergence of class consciousness.
  • Peasant movement: The anger of peasants and traditional zamindars culminated in a number of minor and major revolts. 
  • Famines: The periodic recurrence of famines and the economic depression in the nineteenth century aggravated the situation in rural areas, resulting in many peasant uprisings. 
  • Rights of cultivators: The cultivators lost their long-standing claims to the soil and other customary rights, and they were reduced to the low status of mere tenants.
    • For instance, some of their rights were sacrificed, including the use of pasture and forest lands, irrigation canals, fisheries, homestead plots, and protection from increases in rent.
    • In areas where they were made owners, their conditions are even worse. 
  • Dеbt traps and stagnant productivity: High rеvеnuе demand and the lack of investment in land lеd to peasants falling into dеbt traps and hindеring agricultural productivity.

The drive to collect large revenue was central to British Policy. Sometimes, this led to the development of a land market - the sale and purchase of land. But at other times, the State's demands were so heavy that no purchasers were to be found. The need to collect so much was itself made necessary by the heavy expenditures of the Government in India and its need to send a lot of money to Britain for its expenses there.

Conclusion

  • Optimistic officials had imagined that the new system would transform the Peasants into rich enterprising farmers but this did not happen.
  • Driven by the desire to increase the income from land, revenue officials fixed too high a revenue demand that peasants were unable to pay.
    • Consequently, the Ryots fled the countryside and villages became deserted in many regions.

Other Systems

Taluqdari System

  • The term ‘taluqdar’ has different meanings in different parts of India. In Oudh, taluqdar is a great landholder.
    • But in Bengal, a taluqdar is next to zamindar in extent of land control and social status.
  • The big zamindars themselves had created many taluqs under several denominations, such as, junglburi taluq, mazkuri taluq, shikimi taluq, and so on.
    • These were created partly as a strategy of zamindari management and partly as a fiscal policy measure for raising zamindari funds for specific purposes.
  • After the Permanent Settlement, new varieties of taluqs were created by zamindars.
    • Under the pressure of the Permanent Settlement, many zamindars were creating dependent taluqs denominated as pattani taluq, noabad taluq and osat taluq.

Malguzari System

  • The land tenure prevailing in the erstwhile Central Provinces was known as Malguzari system in which the Malguzar was merely a revenue farmer under the Marathas.
    • When the Marathas came into power in this region, they farmed out the revenues of villages to persons of influence and wealth, who were called Malguzars.
  • During the British Rule, they were given proprietary rights and were held responsible for payment of revenue.
    • If the headman of a village was weak or was for any other reason, unable to answer for the sum the authorities expected, or if a court favourite wanted the village, the headman was replaced without hesitation by a farmer.
  • The farmer, or manager was at first called Mukaddam (the Hindi or Marathi form of Arabic Mugaddam).
  • Under the Malguzari system, the Lambardar/Sadar Lambardar appointed from among the Malguzars, was the revenue engager.
  • Other cultivators were either Absolute occupancy tenant, Occupancy tenant, Sub-tenant, Raiyat-Malik or lessees, who could be ejected from their holdings on various grounds. Malguzar (proprietor or co-sharer) held land under special description, namely, Sir land and Khudkasht land.


POSTED ON 01-03-2024 BY ADMIN
Next previous